•Just as a time-dependent drift may be used to fit many bond or swap rates, a time dependent volatility function may be used to fit many option prices. A particularly simple model with a time-dependent volatility function might be written as follows:
𝑑𝑟 = 𝜆 𝑡 𝑑𝑡 + 𝜎 𝑡 𝑑𝑤
•Unlike the models presented in the last chapter, the volatility of the short rate in the above equation depends on time. If, for example, the function 𝜎(𝑡) were such that 𝜎(1) = 1.26% and 𝜎(2) = 1.20%, then the volatility of the short rate in one year is 126 basis points per year while the volatility of the short rate in two years is 120 basis points per year.
•To illustrate the features of time-dependent volatility, consider the following special case of the above equation that will be called Model 3:
𝑑𝑟 = 𝜆 𝑡 𝑑𝑡 + 𝜎𝑒–αt𝑑𝑤
Here, the volatility of the short rate starts at the constant 𝜎 and then exponentially declines to zero. Volatility could have easily been designed to decline to another constant instead of zero, but Model 3 serves its pedagogical purpose well enough.
•Setting 𝜎 = 126 basis points and 𝛼 = 0.025, this figure shows the standard deviation of the terminal distribution of the short rate at various horizons. The standard deviation rises rapidly with horizon at first but then rises more slowly.
•The behavior of standard deviation as a function of horizon in this figure resembles the impact of mean reversion on horizon standard deviation. In fact, setting the initial volatility and decay rate in Model 3 equal to the volatility and mean reversion rate of the numerical example of the Vasicek model, the standard deviations of the terminal distributions from the two models turn out to be identical. Furthermore, if the time-dependent drift in Model 3 matches the average path of rates in the numerical example of the Vasicek model, then the two models produce exactly the same terminal distributions.
•While these parameterizations of the Vasicek Model of the previous chapter and Model 3 of this chapter give equivalent terminal distributions, the models remain very different in other ways. As is the case for any model without mean reversion, Model 3 is a parallel shift model. Also, the term structure of volatility in Model 3 is flat. Since the volatility in Model 3 changes over time, the term structure of volatility is flat at levels that change over time, but it is still always flat.
•Deterministic volatility functions are popular, particularly among market makers in interest rate options. Consider the example of caplets. At expiration, a caplet pays the difference between the short rate and a strike, if positive, on some notional amount. Furthermore, the value of a caplet depends on the distribution of the short rate at the caplet’s expiration. Therefore, the flexibility of the deterministic functions 𝜆 𝑡 and 𝜎 (𝑡) may be used to match the market prices of caplets expiring on many different dates.
•The arguments for and against using time-dependent volatility are similar to the arguments for and against using a time dependent drift. If the purpose of the model is to quote fixed income options prices that are not easily observable, then a model with time-dependent volatility provides a means of interpolating from known to unknown option prices. If, however, the purpose of the model is to value and hedge fixed income securities, including options, then a model with mean reversion might be preferred for two reasons.
2. Second, the downward-sloping factor structure and term structure of volatility in mean- reverting models capture the behavior of interest rate movements better than parallel shifts and a flat term structure of volatility. It may very well be that the Vasicek model does not capture the behavior of interest rates sufficiently well to be used for a particular valuation or hedging purpose. But in that case, it is unlikely that a parallel shift model calibrated to match caplet prices will be better suited for that purpose.
•The models discussed till now assume that the basis-point volatility of the short rate is independent of the level of the short rate. But this is not true at extreme levels of the short rate.
2. Also, when the short-term rate is very low, its basis-point volatility is limited by the fact that interest rates cannot decline much below zero.
•Hence the basis-point volatility of the short rate is generally taken as an increasing function of the short rate, which is reflected in the risk-neutral dynamics of the Cox-Ingersoll-Ross (CIR) model
Here the parameter 𝜎 is constant, but basis-point volatility is not constant. Annualized basis- point volatility equals 𝜎 𝑟and increases with the level of the short rate.
•Another popular specification is that the basis-point volatility is proportional to rate. In this case the parameter 𝜎 is often called yield volatility. the simplest lognormal model, to be called Model 4, is
𝑑𝑟 = 𝑎𝑟𝑑𝑡 + 𝜎𝑟𝑑𝑤
Here, yield volatility is constant but basis-point volatility equals or and increases with the level of the rate.
•This figure graphs the basis-point volatility as a function of rate for the cases of the constant, square root, and proportional specifications. For comparison purposes, 𝜎 is set in all three cases to be 100 at a short rate of 8%. Mathematically,
𝜎bp = 0.01 = 1%
•As seen in this figure, the CIR and proportional volatility specifications have basis-point volatility increasing with rate but at different speeds. Both models have the basis-point volatility equal to zero at a rate of zero. The property that basis-point volatility equals zero when the short rate is zero, combined with the condition that the drift is positive when the rate is zero, guarantees that the short rate cannot become negative.
•This figure graphs terminal distributions of the short rate after 10 years under the CIR, normal, and lognormal volatility specifications. The parameters have been chosen so that all of the distributions have an expected value of 5% and a standard deviation of 2.32%.
2. The figure also indicates that out-of-the money option prices could differ significantly under the three models. Even if, as in this case, the mean and volatility of the three distributions are the same, the probability of outcomes away from the means are different enough to generate significantly different options prices.
•After applying mathematical tools (which are not a part of the FRM part 2 curriculum)on Model 4, the lognormal model with deterministic drift is given as
𝑑 𝑙𝑛 𝑟 = 𝑎 𝑡 𝑑𝑡 + 𝜎𝑑𝑤
This equation states says that the natural logarithm of the short rate is normally distributed. From FRM Part 1, it is known that a random variable has a lognormal distribution if its natural logarithm has a normal distribution. Therefore, the above equation implies that the short rate has a lognormal distribution.
•The above model may be described as the Ho-Lee model based on the natural logarithm of the short rate instead of on the short rate itself. Adapting the tree for the Ho-Lee model accordingly, the tree for the first three dates is given by this figure.
•To express the previous tree in rate levels, as opposed to the natural logarithm of the rate, each node is exponentiated to give this tree.
•This tree shows that the perturbations to the short rate in a lognormal model are multiplicative as opposed to the additive perturbations in normal models.
This observation, in turn, reveals why the short rate in this model cannot become negative. Since 𝑒x is positive for any value of 𝑥, so long as 𝑟0 is positive every node of the log normal tree results in a positive rate. The tree also reveals why volatility in a lognormal model is expressed as a percentage of the rate. For small values of 𝑥, 𝑒x ≈ 1 + 𝑥. Setting 𝑎1 = 0 𝑎𝑛𝑑 𝑑𝑡 = 1, for example, the top node of date 1 may be approximated as 𝑟0𝑒σ ≈ 𝑟0 1 + 𝜎 . If, for example, 𝜎 = 12.5%, then the short rate in the up-state is 12.5% above the initial short rate. So volatility is clearly a percentage of the rate in equation.
•The final model to be presented in this chapter is a lognormal model with mean reversion called the Black-Karasinski model. The model allows volatility, mean reversion, and the central tendency of the short rate to depend on time, firmly placing the model in the arbitrage free class. A user may, of course, use or remove as much time dependence as desired. The dynamics of the model are written in logarithmic form as
𝑑[𝑙𝑛(𝑟)] = 𝑘(𝑡) (𝑙𝑛(𝜃(𝑡)) — 𝑙𝑛(𝑟))𝑑𝑡 + 𝜎(𝑡)𝑑𝑤
This equation states that that the natural logarithm of the short rate is normally distributed. It reverts to 𝜃(𝑡) at a speed of 𝑘(𝑡) with a volatility of 𝜎 𝑡 Viewed another way, the natural logarithm of the short rate follows a time dependent version of the Vasicek model.
•The final model to be presented in this chapter is a lognormal model with mean reversion called the Black-Karasinski model. The model allows volatility, mean reversion, and the central tendency of the short rate to depend on time, firmly placing the model in the arbitrage free class. A user may, of course, use or remove as much time dependence as desired. The dynamics of the model are written in logarithmic form as
𝑑[𝑙𝑛(𝑟)] = 𝑘(𝑡) (𝑙𝑛(𝜃(𝑡)) — 𝑙𝑛(𝑟))𝑑𝑡 + 𝜎(𝑡)𝑑𝑤
This equation states that that the natural logarithm of the short rate is normally distributed. It reverts to 𝜃(𝑡) at a speed of 𝑘(𝑡) with a volatility of 𝜎 𝑡 . Viewed another way, the natural logarithm of the short rate follows a time-dependent version of the Vasicek model.
•As in the previous section, the corresponding tree may be written in terms of the rate or the natural logarithm of the rate. In terms of rate, the process over the first date is given in this figure.
•The variable 𝑟1 is introduced for readability. The natural logarithms of the rates in the up and down-states are 𝑙𝑛𝑟1 + 𝜎 1 𝑑𝑡 and 𝑙𝑛𝑟1 — 𝜎 1 𝑑𝑡 respectively. A little algebra shows that the tree recombines only if
•This above condition for recombination suggests that the mean reversion speed is completely determined by the time-dependent volatility function. But it has been observed earlier in this chapter that the mean reversion controls the term structure of volatility whereas time- dependent volatility controls the future volatility of the short-term rate. To create a model flexible enough to control mean reversion and time-dependent volatility separately, the model has to construct a recombining tree without imposing this constraint of mean reversion speed being completely determined by the time-dependent volatility function.. To do so it allows the length of the time step, 𝑑𝑡, to change over time.
•A little algebra now shows that the tree recombines if
The length of the first time step can be set arbitrarily. The length of the second time step is set to satisfy the above equation, allowing the user freedom in choosing the mean reversion and volatility functions independently.